General Discussion Undecided where to post - do it here. |
Reply to Thread New Thread |
![]() |
#21 |
|
|
![]() |
![]() |
#22 |
|
Ross Douthat has a post over at the NYT today that provides a quick overview of the recent arguments about the VAT, plus his own take on its political feasibility...
Will We Get a V.A.T.? |
![]() |
![]() |
#23 |
|
This blog post that I linked to in the Healthcare Reform Thread deserves to be linked to again here. Lots of interesting information on optimal tax policy.
The optimal size of government is a partisan issue. The optimal tax mix isn't. |
![]() |
![]() |
#24 |
|
|
![]() |
![]() |
#25 |
|
|
![]() |
![]() |
#26 |
|
Historically it's been Canada. Every year except this one Canada has had far higher structural unemployment. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/VAT |
![]() |
![]() |
#27 |
|
There's a good article on the U.S. national debt in the Spring 2010 issue of National Affairs. Here's what it had to say on taxes...
Fifth, policymakers must understand that while some tax increases will almost certainly be required, not all taxes are created equal — and that which form the tax hikes take will make a big difference to our future prosperity. Taxes on income, for example, are usually worse for the economy than taxes on consumption. That is why one finds a rising chorus of economists recommending the introduction of a value-added tax, rather than higher income taxes, if our nation decides it wants to support substantially higher government spending. High tax rates similarly tend to be worse for the economy than low rates — which is why economists usually favor reforms that eliminate special exemptions and deductions, thus broadening the tax base and allowing for lower rates. Finally, it is preferable to levy taxes on behaviors we want to discourage rather than on those that are necessary for economic growth. Where appropriate, taxes on pollution, for instance, should be preferred over taxes on working, saving, or investing. This approach to taxes is derived from a broader — and crucial — imperative that policymakers should heed as they seek to improve our fiscal health: Promote growth, or at least minimize the harm to it. As lawmakers consider changes to spending and tax policies, they must always consider carefully the effects their proposals will have on economic expansion. For instance, policymakers should not always assume that a larger government will necessarily translate into weaker economic performance. A few years ago, Peter Lindert — an economist at the University of California, Davis — looked across countries and across time in an effort to answer the question, "Is the welfare state a free lunch?" He found that countries with high levels of government spending did not perform any worse, economically speaking, than countries with low levels of government spending. The result was surprising, given the usual intuition that a larger government would levy higher taxes and engage in more income redistribution — both of which would undermine economic growth. Lindert found that the reason for this apparent paradox is that countries with large welfare states try to minimize the extent to which government actions undermine the economy. Thus, high-budget nations tend to adopt more efficient tax systems — with flatter rates and greater reliance on consumption taxes — than do countries with lower budgets. High-budget countries also adopt more efficient benefits systems — taking care, for example, to minimize the degree to which subsidy programs discourage beneficiaries from working. Of course, the United States should work to reduce the economic inefficiencies in our current policies regardless of whatever else we decide. But such efforts will be even more important if America chooses — either explicitly or, more likely, implicitly — to become a higher-budget country. Our existing tax system is notoriously inefficient and will not scale well to higher revenue demands. If policymakers decide they want to boost revenues, they will need to embrace a more efficient tax system — perhaps including value-added taxes — even if they are perceived as less progressive. Similarly, as spending programs expand, policymakers should focus on ways to reduce the anti-work incentives implicit in such programs. (The incentive for early retirement created by the structure of Social Security benefits would be a good place to start.) These kinds of reforms would make sense regardless of the direction of federal spending policy — so leaders across the political spectrum should be able to agree on many of them. http://www.nationalaffairs.com/publi...ica-in-the-red |
![]() |
![]() |
#28 |
|
What the **** do you think people ****ing save for, you twits? To roll around in giant stacks of money like Uncle ****ing Scrooge?
The only real difference between a consumption tax and a flat earned income tax is simply that existent wealth is taxed by the consumption tax (it's actually a free lunch as far as expropriating the rich goes!). Also, with a consumption tax, savings get taxed later, while with an earned income tax they get taxed now. However the NPV of the two tax bills is equal. |
![]() |
![]() |
#29 |
|
|
![]() |
![]() |
#30 |
|
|
![]() |
![]() |
#31 |
|
They pay an equal percentage of their consumption. Savings are deferred consumption. Eventually the rich person or their descendants will pay the tax. |
![]() |
![]() |
#32 |
|
The only difference between a flat tax and the VAT is in where it's collected and possibly the treatment of already-existent capital (the VAT expropriates those who already have large sums of money relative to the flat tax). The incentive effects are identical. |
![]() |
![]() |
#33 |
|
So how does a VAT affect exports, compared to a sales tax? I'm going to borrow the example from the VAT wikipedia article- |
![]() |
![]() |
#34 |
|
I should have said exporter. 'The exporter would get a refund...'
You do not need to be a manufacturer to claim refunds on inputs. Pretty well all businesses are part of the GST system. Importers/exporters would collect GST on imports that are sold on into Canada and claim refunds on products purchased domestically and exported. The difference between GST collected on sales and GST paid on inputs is paid to or refunded from the feds. This is where Ben is mistaken. The GST has zero effect on businesses in the chain of transactions from originators to consumers. Anything paid is deducted from what is collected to determine what is remitted, and the business will get a refund if they have significant non-taxable sales. |
![]() |
![]() |
#35 |
|
|
![]() |
![]() |
#36 |
|
Ben has been saying that the GST that came into effect in Canada ~1990 has been a job killer.
That is misleading. The GST replaced an older federal tax that was levied on manufactured goods, including exports, and was not levied on imports. It was hidden as it was charged by the manufacturer to wholesalers and retailers, which is why just about nobody knows it even existed. That tax was then marked up in prices to consumers. That tax was indeed a job killer. The GST is not. |
![]() |
Reply to Thread New Thread |
Currently Active Users Viewing This Thread: 1 (0 members and 1 guests) | |
|